History of the Minimum Wage 1938 — The minimum wage was first enacted into law as part of the Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA) of 1938. The original minimum wage applied to workers engaged in interstate commerce and the production of goods for interstate commerce. In 1938, this applied to roughly 11. 0 million workers out of a total of 54. 9 million workers.
The minimum wage was set at $0. 25 per hour. 1961 — Amendments to the minimum wage law extend coverage primarily to employees in large retail and service trades as well as local transit, construction, and gasoline service station employees. 1966 — Amendments to the minimum wage law extend coverage to state and local government employees of hospitals, nursing homes, and schools and to employees of laundries, dry cleaners, large hotels and motels, restaurants, and farms. Subsequent amendments extended coverage to the remaining federal, state and local government employee not protected in 1966, to certain workers in retail and service trades previously exempted, and to certain domestic workers in private household employment.
The 20-percent increase in the federal minimum wage scheduled to occur over the next year may not be the best way to boost the incomes of low-skilled workers and their families. This article explores the purpose and impact of the minimum wage in an effort to discover whether it is a good idea. Proponents of the minimum wage argue that it ensures a “living wage” for workers who might otherwise be underpaid, while opponents claim it costs hundreds of thousands of workers their jobs and reduces new hires of unskilled workers. About 10 percent of workers will be directly affected by the two increases in the minimum wage Congress authorized in 1996. The first increase, which took effect on October 1, boosted the minimum wage from $4.
25 to $4. 75. The second increase, scheduled for September 1, 1997, will raise the wage floor to $5. 15. A Brief History?A public outcry over wages and working conditions in turn-of-the-century sweatshops led to the first minimum wages in the United States.
Several states, beginning with Massachusetts in 1912, regulated minimum wages, maximum hours and working conditions for women and minors. A national minimum wage was created in 1938 when President Franklin D. Roosevelt signed the Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA). Initially set at 25 cents per hour, the wage floor applied to industries engaged in interstate commerce and covered about one-fifth of the labor force. The FLSA also required overtime pay and set restrictions on child labor. The basic goal of the minimum wage is to guarantee workers a “fair wage.
” Congress determines increases in the federal minimum wage and has usually set it at about one-half the average manufacturing wage. (Table 1 summarizes the history of the federal minimum wage. ) Since the minimum wage is set in nominal terms, its real value declines as prices rise until Congress raises the wage floor again, creating the sawtooth pattern evident in Chart 1. ?As shown in the chart, the minimum wage fell dramatically relative to the average manufacturing wage during the 1980s, prompting one-third of the states to impose state minimum wages above the federal level. Over time, Congress has greatly expanded the coverage of the FLSA, and almost 90 percent of workers now must be paid at least the minimum wage.
Most businesses with annual sales of less than $500,000 are exempt from the minimum wage standard. Concerns that the wage floor would reduce employment for certain groups of workers led to the creation of “subminimum wages. ” The federal wage floor has usually been lower for students, and in 1989, the subminimum wage was expanded to cover all teenagers. Under the 1996 law, employers will still be able to pay teenagers $4.
25 for up to 90 days. Tipped employees may also be paid less than the wage floor since the law currently includes a “tip credit” that allows employers to pay workers $2. 13 an hour and credit tips for the rest of the wage floor. l “top”Who Earns the Minimum Wage?Before we assess the effects of minimum wage hikes, it is useful to examine the demographics of those earning the minimum wage to determine whether the policy helps low-skilled workers who support families or merely boosts the incomes of middle-class teenagers. Relatively few workers earn exactly the minimum wage–only 5. 3 percent in 1995.
Fewer than 10 percent of workers earned between $4. 25 and $5. 15. ?There are two main types of minimum wage workers: youths who are earning a starting wage, often while still in school, and adult women for whom the minimum wage is a primary source of household income. In 1995, more than one-third of all workers earning the federal minimum wage were teenagers, and another one-fifth were aged 20-24.
The vast majority were part-time workers, and over 60 percent of workers paid the federal minimum wage were female. Table 2 summarizes the characteristics of minimum wage workers. Minimum wage workers are highly concentrated in the retail trade and service sectors and in small businesses. Over four-fifths of workers paid the federal minimum wage in 1993 were employed by retail trade or service establishments. More than one-half of all workers earning the minimum wage were employed at establishments with fewer than 25 employees, and about 85 percent were employed by establishments with fewer than 100 employees.
In addition, a higher fraction of workers employed by small businesses are paid the minimum wage; almost 4 percent of employees at establishments with fewer than 25 employees earned the minimum wage, compared with less than 1 percent at establishments with more than 250 employees. Many economists believe that the minimum wage raises the wages of middle-class teens while doing little to help the working poor get out of poverty. Edward Gramlich (1976) found that any income gains among teenagers resulting from the minimum wage are about evenly split between high-income and low-income families. The vast majority of minimum wage workers are not the primary wage earner in a poor family; Richard Burkhauser and T.
Aldrich Finegan (1989) estimated that in the mid-1980s only 7 percent of low-wage workers were heads of families living in poverty. Burkhauser, Kenneth Couch and David Wittenberg (1996) found that almost 40 percent of all workers directly affected by the minimum wage increases in 1990 and 1991 were from families in the top half of the income distribution, with 4 percent of affected workers in the top decile. The minimum wage does have the potential to raise the incomes of some poor households, particularly those headed by women. About 40 percent of poor adults worked in 1994, and low-wage workers contribute about one-half of household earnings. Over one-fourth of all workers in the lowest family income decile were affected by the 1990 and 1991 federal minimum wage increases, according to Burkhauser, Couch and Wittenberg.
Because women tend to have lower earnings than men, working women are more likely to be in poverty. In 1987, the earnings of nearly 18 percent of working female household heads were less than the poverty level. However, the minimum wage is not high enough to lift most single-earner families out of poverty. After the federal minimum reaches $5.
15 in 1997, a full-time, year-round worker will earn about $10,700 annually before taxes, less than the poverty level for a family with two children. More than one-half of all families headed by single women with children were below the poverty level in 1993. In addition, low-skilled adults may be the most likely to be laid off when the minimum wage is raised. Minimum wage increases may draw more-skilled workers into the labor market and cause employers to switch from low-skilled workers to high-skilled ones.
Indeed, Kevin Lang (1994) found that minimum wage increases appear to have caused restaurants to substitute teenagers for lower skilled adult workers. Similarly, research by David Neumark and William Wascher (1995) suggests that employers substitute higher skilled teens for lower skilled teens when the minimum wage is raised. Youths who earn the minimum wage are soon likely to earn higher wages, while adults with low levels of education are more likely to get stuck at the wage floor. Ralph Smith and Bruce Vavrichek (1992) followed a group of workers earning the minimum wage in the mid-1980s and found that over 60 percent of them were earning higher wages after one year, with a median wage gain of 20 percent.
However, over one-third of those workers who were still employed a year later did not experience any wage increase, even before adjusting for inflation. These workers tended to be older and have less education than workers who experienced a wage increase. These demographics suggest that a substantial minority of low-wage workers might receive even lower wages in the absence of a minimum wage. Teens and low-skilled women are the primary earners of the minimum wage. If the minimum wage is designed to ensure a “living wage” for families, it fails to accomplish this because it does not raise a single-earner household with children out of poverty. Although the minimum wage raises some workers’ wages, it also may hurt the very workers it is designed to help since businesses may respond to minimum wage increases by reducing the number of employees, cutting the number of hours worked by employees and/or raising prices.
l “top”Effects of Minimum Wage IncreasesNeoclassical economic theory predicts that a minimum wage increase will reduce the number of low-wage workers demanded by employers. Under this model, employment of workers who initially earned less than the new wage floor should fall when the minimum wage is increased. If employers need to raise the wages of other workers to maintain a wage hierarchy within the firm, the ripple effect can cause even greater employment losses. Economists have tested this theory by examining the effect of minimum wage increases on employment among teenagers.
Most studies have found that an increase in the minimum wage slightly lowers teenage employment. l “1” 1 In their 1982 survey of minimum wage research, Charles Brown, Curtis Gilroy and Andrew Kohen conclude that a 10-percent increase in the minimum wage reduces teen employment by 1 to 3 percent. In a recent study, Donald Deere, Kevin M. Murphy and Finis Welch (1995) conclude that the 1990 and 1991 increases in the federal minimum wage caused teen employment to be at least 10 percent lower than it would otherwise have been. Several recent studies, however, have found that minimum wage increases appear not to reduce employment among low-wage workers. David Card and Alan Krueger (1995) find that increases in federal and state minimum wages during the 1980s and early 1990s did not reduce employment among teenagers or workers at fast-food restaurants.
Indeed, their research suggests that the increases may even have slightly raised employment. In a particularly controversial study, Card and Krueger find that a 90-cent increase in New Jersey’s minimum wage in 1992 appears to have increased employment at fast-food restaurants relative to neighboring Pennsylvania, which did not experience a minimum wage increase. This research, and its implications for public policy, has been strongly criticized on methodological and theoretical grounds. There are several potential reasons employment might not fall when the minimum wage rises.
First, an increase in the minimum wage simply might not be large enough to raise wages. Even if the minimum wage hike raises workers’ pay, there are several possible scenarios in which employment might not fall or might even increase. One such possibility is monopsony, in which a firm can attract more workers if it increases the wage. If workers with similar skills have different reservation wages–the lowest wage at which they are willing to work–then an employer will first hire those workers with the lowest reservation wages. As a firm hires more workers, it must raise the wage, but employers may not be willing to pay higher wages to all workers to attract additional workers.
Under this theory, a minimum wage increase forces the employer to offer a higher wage and increases the number of persons willing to work, thereby possibly increasing employment. l “2” Another possibility is that existing workers become more productive when the minimum wage is raised or higher skilled workers enter the labor market, and increased output balances out the higher cost of labor to employers. These explanations for why minimum wage increases may not reduce employment are not particularly compelling or realistic. Monopsony power effectively requires that an individual firm have a monopoly on jobs.
This almost certainly does not characterize the labor market for most firms, particularly those that employ low-skill, low-wage labor–just consider the number of fast-food restaurants in your town and think about whether any one of those firms can be considered a monopoly provider of jobs for low-skill workers. In addition, if a firm can increase output and potentially earn greater profits by offering a higher wage, it should be willing to offer the higher wage without the mandate of the minimum wage. Another reason employment might not fall when the minimum wage increases is that businesses may reduce hours while keeping the same number of workers. This practice potentially leaves workers better off if they are able to earn the same amount as before by working fewer hours at a higher wage. However, there is no current empirical evidence to support or refute this hypothesis. Economists have also suggested that employers may replace labor with capital over the long run in response to minimum wage hikes, in which case the true impact of a minimum wage increase cannot be observed for several years.
Employers may raise prices as well as reduce employment when the minimum wage increases. This effect has been documented in fast-food prices, which is not surprising since most restaurant employees’ wages are near the minimum wage. Several researchers have found that a 10-percent increase in the minimum wage is correlated with a 1-percent increase in fast-food prices. Minimum wage increases can contribute to inflation through two channels: firms may raise prices to recoup higher labor costs, and workers earning higher incomes may raise aggregate demand, creating further upward pressure on prices. l “top”Is There a Better Way?The historical basis of the minimum wage was to prevent the exploitation of labor. Proponents of the federal minimum argue that it is still needed almost 60 years after its creation to ensure a living wage.
Although the wage floor does raise wages for some workers, it can also reduce employment opportunities and raise prices. Minimum wage supporters often argue that the poverty-reducing effects of the minimum wage outweigh the potential small disemployment effects. However, most minimum wage workers are not from impoverished families, and the least skilled, lowest wage workers are the most likely to be laid off when the minimum wage is increased. There are better ways for government to help the working poor, particularly those who are supporting families. One option is to use tax policy to ensure that workers earn at least the poverty level for their household.
The minimum wage could be replaced by a combination of tax credits and a negative income tax. This approach has several advantages. A tax policy could easily be targeted to help only workers from poor families instead of benefiting all workers regardless of need. While the minimum wage acts as a tax on businesses that hire low-skilled workers, an alternative program could be funded with general tax revenues. A tax-based policy can be both more equitable and more efficient than the minimum wage. In addition, a tax-based policy would offer low-skilled workers greater opportunity to acquire job-market experience.
The minimum wage can be a disincentive for firms to hire low-skilled workers, reducing the ability of workers to get a foot in the door and learn skills through on-the-job training. Of course, a primary disadvantage of eliminating the minimum wage is that some firms might be able to exploit workers and pay them below-market wages. The United States already has a policy similar to the one outlined above: the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), which provides a wage subsidy to low-income workers with dependents. In 1996, for example, a worker who has two children and earns less than $8,890 receives a 40-percent wage subsidy under the EITC. Benefits are phased out as earnings increase and families rise above the poverty level. Unlike the minimum wage, the program only benefits low-income workers, and the benefit is based partially on family size.
The EITC also can move more working families with only one wage earner out of poverty than can the minimum wage. l “3”Given that programs like the EITC are a better way to “make work pay” than the minimum wage, why do we continue to have a minimum wage’surveys show the vast majority of the American public supports the minimum wage. Politicians support it because it offers a way to redistribute income through an indirect tax on businesses, whereas tax-based programs such as the EITC require government funding in an era of budget deficits. Some members of Congress have recently even called for reducing the EITC to reduce government expenditures. Unless the public and politicians recognize that a taxed-based program is a better way to help the working poor, the federal minimum wage policy almost certainly will continue to exist. l “top”Notes 1.
Economists focus on the effect of the minimum wage on employment instead of on unemployment since the minimum wage potentially affects labor supply as well as employment. Several studies have found that teen labor supply falls when the minimum wage increases, and, therefore, teen unemployment can decline even though the teen employment falls. l “C”2. Dynamic monopsony, a variant of the monopsony model, is another theory for why employment might increase when the minimum wage rises.
In this model, the minimum wage helps solve imperfect information problems. In one plausible version of the dynamic monopsony model, an increase in the minimum wage raises employment by reducing labor turnover. l “C”3. A worker with two children earning the minimum wage of $4. 25 in 1996 would have earned $8,840 annually.
A minimum wage of $5. 15 raises the family’s income to $10,712, while the current EITC program raises it to $12,376. The poverty level for this family was $12,278 in 1995. l “D”l “top” References Brown, C. , C. Gilroy and A.
Kohen (1982), “The Effect of the Minimum Wage on Employment and Unemployment,” Journal of Economic Literature 20 (June): 487-528. Burkhauser, R. , K. Couch and D.
Wittenberg (1996), ” ‘Who Gets What’ from Minimum Wage Hikes,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 49 (April): 547-52. ——, and T. A. Finegan (1989), “The Minimum Wage and the Poor: The End of a Relationship,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 8 (Winter): 53-71.
Card, D. , and A. Krueger (1995), Myth and Measurement (Princeton, N. J. : Princeton University Press).
Deere, D. , K. M. Murphy and F. Welch (1995), “Employment and the 1990-1991 Minimum Wage Hike,” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 85 (May): 232-37. Gramlich, E.
(1976), “Impact of Minimum Wages on Other Wages, Employment, and Family Incomes,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 409-51. Lang, K. (1994), “The Effect of Minimum Wage Laws on the Distribution of Employment: Theory and Evidence,” Working Paper, Boston University. Neumark, D. , and W.
Wascher (1995), “The Effects of Minimum Wages on Teenage Employment and Enrollment: Evidence from Matched CPS Surveys,” NBER Working Paper No. 5092, April. Smith, R. , and B.
Vavrichek (1992), “The Wage Mobility of Minimum Wage Workers,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46 (October): 82-88. l “top” The Southwest Economy is published six times annually by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views expressed are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System. Articles may be reprinted on the condition that the source is credited and a copy is provided to the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The Southwest Economy is available free of charge by writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, P.
O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX 75265-5906, or by telephoning (214) 922-5257. l “top” Back to “” Update: January 12, 1997 “http://www. csus. edu/indiv/j/jensena/””mailto:emailprotected“”http://www. csus.
edu/sba””http://www. csus. edu” Minimum Wage, 2000 StyleBy “/thoughts/archive/bios. asp?author=21″11/11/99 12:50 PM ETTuesday, the U.
S. Senate voted to increase the minimum wage by $1 per hour to $6. 15 in three steps by March 2002. This legislative move came with little fanfare, but is notable because it was based on a Republican-sponsored measure. In essence, the lack of acrimonious debate on the minimum wage that has accompanied previous increases shows how close the two major parties are on many economic issues. Still, there are a few differences between Democratic and Republican proposals on the minimum wage, especially with regard to helping small businesses defray the additional costs that would come from higher wages.
Maybe even more important is the fact that the tight labor market has already raised many workers above minimum wage levels, preempting major opposition from the business lobbies. Finally, it is unlikely that the Republican proposal will reach the President before next year (and far from assured that he will then sign it) and inflation, although low, will continue to eat into the value of the minimum wage. According to one estimate, nearly 12 million workers will be directly affected by the outcome. Brief History. In 1938, with the passage of the Fair Labor Standards Act, Congress established the “/top25/t25_minimum.
stm”. Since then, the minimum wage has been raised 17 times and has expanded to include millions of workers not covered at the law’s initial passage. Along with the increases in the minimum wage and its coverage has come much debate over its impact on “/economy/releases/dyn_release. asp?r=usa_employ” and the overall economy.
Although politicians in both parties rarely dispute the concept and even necessity of a wage floor, the means of attaining a fair wage is often debated. Current Bill. If passed, the Republican bill would increase the minimum wage in three stages over a period of 28 months. The first increase of 35 cents would come in March 2000, followed by another 35 cent rise in March 2001 and a final 30 cent increase in March 2002.
Included in this measure is a tax package intended to provide tax breaks and incentives for those small businesses that would be most financially burdened by the additional cost of employing minimum wage earners. The total $18. 4 billion worth of tax cuts would be implemented over a period of five years and financed by the anticipated surpluses in the federal budget. President Clinton, however, has threatened to veto any measure that cuts into the budget surplus, and passage is not guaranteed. Just before the approval of the Republican bill, Senate members voted against an alternative fashioned by the Democratic Party. This measure allowed for a similar increase in the minimum wage, but would be completed in two equal sums over a 13-month time frame, more than two times faster than the GOP bill.
Also, the tax relief provided to small businesses in the Democratic version of the bill would be only half of that allowed for in the Republican proposal. These few differences in these otherwise similar bills are the result of opposing views on the economic impact of a higher minimum wage. Republicans favor a slower phasing-in of the wage increase, asserting that minimum wage workers are more likely and more quickly given pay increases based on their contribution to the company. Thus, the slower rate at which the minimum wage is increased is insignificant given that many wages are likely to rise above the minimum anyway. In terms of its impact on employment, Republicans oppose the Democratic bill on the grounds that the tax advantages it provides to small business owners are not enough help in offsetting higher employment costs.
Republicans claimed the Democratic bill would cause the unemployment of up to 500,000 workers as owners trim payrolls. Some academic studies support this view and suggest that a 10% increase in the minimum wage leads to the unemployment of 100,000 workers. Therefore, the proposed 19% increase could leave nearly 200,000 people unemployed. However, other studies disagree and find no significant job losses from the types of minimum wage hikes that are being debated.
By slowly phasing-in the minimum wage increase, the economy should be able to absorb most of the potential job losses. Further, the tax increases that Democrats proposed to help pay for the tax incentives provided for in their measure will further exacerbate the effect on business costs. Among these increases is the restoration of the Superfund environmental tax and a strategy to close corporate tax shelters. The Republican bill, on the other hand, does not include tax hikes. In defense of the Democratic bill are those who believe the GOP measure is too slow-moving.
Despite the number of increases to the wage floor since its introduction, the minimum wage continually fails to keep up with the rate of “/economy/releases/dyn_release. asp?r=usa_cpi”. ?In fact, the annual income of a family of three, working full-time at the minimum wage falls well below the poverty line, constituting only 84% of what would be considered a poverty level income. Decelerating the pace at which the minimum wage increase is introduced into the economy only aggravates this problem. In addition, Democrats argue that the structure of the Republican tax package, which allows for higher 401(k) contribution limits and other pension expansions, benefits large rather than small businesses.
For this reason, the passage of the bill would not only impose an increased financial burden on small businesses, but would also reduce their contribution to the national economy. Outside of the debate over which party’s bill best serves the public interest, the overall effects of a higher minimum wage remain constant. An increased wage floor improves overall morale and keeps worker turnover rates lower. In effect, this increase in productivity helps to balance out at least some of the additional expense of higher wages.
Likewise, a guaranteed wage helps to boost consumer confidence and spending, having a positive impact on the national economy. Even with the proposed $1. 00 increase, the fact that it is spread over time will probably lower its real value to less than 4 percent per annum (after adjusting for inflation). And as seen in the chart above, the Federal minimum wage has lost the battle against inflation since the late 1960s.
Many cities, recognizing this fact, are enacting “living wage” laws that set their lowest wages at over $8 per hour in an effort to pull more workers above the poverty line. Nonetheless, the best course to getting higher wages is through economic growth and greater general demand for labor of the type we are now seeing such that minimum wage laws have less economic relevance. If, or better yet, when, the economy turns down, debates over minimum wages could intensify greatly with an outcome that is hard to predict. Further growth in general economic prosperity, on the other hand, would bring greater pressure from the living wage side and might make current debates over a $1. 00 hike in the minimum wage seem minimal indeed.
????During the public debate about raising the minimum wage a few years ago, House Republican leader Dick Armey vowed to oppose the hike with “every fiber of my being. “Washington Post, Feb. 3, 1995Work should be a bridge out of poverty, but for many it is not. About 3. 4 million workers worked full-time and year-round in 1997, yet they and their families lived in poverty. Although the minimum wage rose in 1997 to $5.
15 an hour, this increase did not restore the minimum wage to its historic value. In the past, the minimum wage provided enough income to lift a family of three out of poverty. During the 1960s and 1970s, the poverty level for a family of three was roughly equal to the yearly earnings of a full-time, year-round worker earning the minimum wage. The minimum wage, however, remained unchanged at $3. 35 an hour from 1981 until April 1990, and thus, minimum wage earnings slipped significantly below the poverty level.
Recent increases have not restored all the lost value. To reach the poverty level for a family of three in 1999 ($13,290), a full-time, year-round worker would need to earn $6. 39 an hour$1. 24 more than the current minimum wage level. A 1999 study by the U. S.
Conference of Mayors found that 67 percent of adults seeking emergency food aid were workers. Officials in 58 percent of the cities surveyed identified low-paying jobs as a primary cause of hunger. ?A full-time, year-round minimum wage worker in 1999 earned only $10,712$2,578 less than the $13,290 needed to raise a family of three out of poverty. Note: Annual minimum wage earnings are calculated by assuming a person worked 40 hours a week for 52 weeks. (p) Preliminary.
This number is a preliminary estimate from the U. S. Census Bureau. The final 1999 poverty line estimate will be available from the Census Bureau later this year.
Sources: U. S. Census Bureau, Table 6. “http://www. census.
gov/hhes/poverty/histpov/hstpov1. html”; U. S. Department of Labor, “http://www. dol. gov/dol/esa/public/minwage/chart.
htm”; U. S. Census Bureau, Poverty in the United States: 1997, p. 60-201, September 1998; U. S. Census Bureau, Poverty in the United States: 1998, p.
60-207, September 1999; U. S. Census Bureau, “http://www. census. gov/hhes/poverty/threshld/99prelim.
html”, Jan. 19, 2000. February 15, 1995 50 Years of Research on the Minimum WageIntroductionFor many years it has been a matter of conventional wisdom among economists that the minimum wage causes fewer jobs to exist than would be the case without it. This is simply a matter of price theory, taught in every economics textbook, requiring no elaborate analysis to justify.
Were this not the case, there would be no logical reason why the minimum wage could not be set at $10, $100, or $1 million per hour. Historically, defenders of the minimum wage have not disputed the disemployment effects of the minimum wage, but argued that on balance the working poor were better off. In other words, the higher incomes of those with jobs offset the lower incomes of those without jobs, as a result of the minimum wage l “levitan”. Now, the Clinton Administration is advancing the novel economic theory that modest increases in the minimum wage will have no impact whatsoever on employment. This proposition is based entirely on the work of three economists: David Card and Alan Krueger of Princeton, and Lawrence Katz of Harvard. Their studies of increases in the minimum wage in California, Texas and New Jersey apparently found no loss of jobs among fast food restaurants that were surveyed before and after the increase l “card-92b”, l “krueger”, and l “katz”.
While it is not yet clear why Card, Katz and Krueger got the results that they did, it is clear that their findings are directly contrary to virtually every empirical study ever done on the minimum wage. These studies were exhaustively surveyed by the Minimum Wage Study Commission, which concluded that a 10% increase in the minimum wage reduced teenage employment by 1% to 3%. The following survey of the academic research on the minimum wage is designed to give nonspecialists a sense of just how isolated the Card, Krueger and Katz studies are. It will also indicate that the minimum wage has wide-ranging negative effects that go beyond unemployment. For example, higher minimum wages encourage employers to cut back on training, thus depriving low wage workers of an important means of long-term advancement, in return for a small increase in current income. For many workers this is a very bad trade-off, but one for which the law provides no alternative.
?Summary of Research on the Minimum WageThe minimum wage reduces employment. Currie and Fallick (1993), Gallasch (1975), Gardner (1981), Peterson (1957), Peterson and Stewart (1969). The minimum wage reduces employment more among teenagers than adults. Adie (1973); Brown, Gilroy and Kohen (1981a, 1981b); Fleisher (1981); Hammermesh (1982); Meyer and Wise (1981, 1983a); Minimum Wage Study Commission (1981); Neumark and Wascher (1992); Ragan (1977); Vandenbrink (1987); Welch (1974, 1978); Welch and Cunningham (1978).
The minimum wage reduces employment most among black teenage males. Al-Salam, Quester, and Welch (1981), Iden (1980), Mincer (1976), Moore (1971), Ragan (1977), Williams (1977a, 1977b). The minimum wage helped South African whites at the expense of blacks. Bauer (1959). The minimum wage hurts blacks generally. Behrman, Sickles and Taubman (1983); Linneman (1982).
The minimum wage hurts the unskilled. Krumm (1981). The minimum wage hurts low wage workers. Brozen (1962), Cox and Oaxaca (1986), Gordon (1981). The minimum wage hurts low wage workers particularly during cyclical downturns. Kosters and Welch (1972), Welch (1974).
The minimum wage increases job turnover. Hall (1982). The minimum wage reduces average earnings of young workers. Meyer and Wise (1983b). The minimum wage drives workers into uncovered jobs, thus lowering wages in those sectors.
Brozen (1962), Tauchen (1981), Welch (1974). The minimum wage reduces employment in low-wage industries, such as retailing. Cotterman (1981), Douty (1960), Fleisher (1981), Hammermesh (1981), Peterson (1981). The minimum wage hurts small businesses generally.
Kaun (1965). The minimum wage causes employers to cut back on training. Hashimoto (1981, 1982), Leighton and Mincer (1981), Ragan (1981). The minimum wage has long-term effects on skills and lifetime earnings. Brozen (1969), Feldstein (1973). The minimum wage leads employers to cut back on fringe benefits.
McKenzie (1980), Wessels (1980). The minimum wage encourages employers to install labor-saving devices. Trapani and Moroney (1981). The minimum wage hurts low-wage regions, such as the South and rural areas. Colberg (1960, 1981), Krumm (1981). The minimum wage increases the number of people on welfare.
Brandon (1995), Leffler (1978). The minimum wage hurts the poor generally. Stigler (1946). The minimum wage does little to reduce poverty.
Bonilla (1992), Brown (1988), Johnson and Browning (1983), Kohen and Gilroy (1981), Parsons (1980), Smith and Vavrichek (1987). The minimum wage helps upper income families. Bell (1981), Datcher and Loury (1981), Johnson and Browning (1981), Kohen and Gilroy (1981). The minimum wage helps unions.
Linneman (1982), Cox and Oaxaca (1982). The minimum wage lowers the capital stock. McCulloch (1981). The minimum wage increases inflationary pressure. Adams (1987), Brozen (1966), Gramlich (1976), Grossman (1983).
The minimum wage increases teenage crime rates. Hashimoto (1987), Phillips (1981). The minimum wage encourages employers to hire illegal aliens. Beranek (1982). Few workers are permanently stuck at the minimum wage. Brozen (1969), Smith and Vavrichek (1992).
The minimum wage has had a massive impact on unemployment in Puerto Rico. Freeman and Freeman (1991), Rottenberg (1981b). The minimum wage has reduced employment in foreign countries. Canada: Forrest (1982); Chile: Corbo (1981); Costa Rica: Gregory (1981); France: Rosa (1981). Characteristics of minimum wage workers Employment Policies Institute (1994), Haugen and Mellor (1990), Kniesner (1981), Mellor (1987), Mellor and Haugen (1986), Smith and Vavrichek (1987), Van Giezen (1994Words/ Pages : 5,749 / 24